David Rosenberg: Tighter immigration targets could tip Bank of Canada rate below 2%

canada-immigration-1105-ph
Under the new immigration targets, the net flow of new arrivals and overall population growth in Canada will turn negative for two years. (Credit: Getty Images)

By David Rosenberg and Dylan Smith

The beleaguered Justin Trudeau government is finally pumping the brakes on its immigration targets after presiding over the biggest population inflow surge since the post-Second World War boom. 

Compared to the prior aggressive targets, this will mean slower labour force growth and hopefully stem the relentless multi-year erosion in real gross domestic product (GDP) per capita because it has become abundantly clear that Canada’s economic infrastructure has been insufficient in absorbing the unprecedented wave of international immigration inflows these past three years.

What is this shift in policy, exactly? The updated three-year targets have Canada welcoming 390,000 new permanent residents in 2025, down from 500,000 in 2024, with similar adjustments to the targets for 2026 and 2027. But the real change comes with the introduction of targets for temporary residents for the first time, which has accounted for the majority of the immigrant-led population boom in recent years (Canada has averaged 573,000 net arrivals per year over the past seven years, topping out at 1.2 million in 2023). 

There are currently more than three million temporary residents in Canada — over seven per cent of the population. The new targets aim to reduce that figure to five per cent, which is a huge shock over a short time frame. Since a large share of the permanent residency target will be allocated to temporary residents currently in Canada, the net flow of new arrivals and overall population growth will turn slightly negative for two years.

Let’s unpack what this means for the economy. The effect on the labour market appears straightforward at face value. The labour force will grow at a slower pace, implying a tighter labour market than would otherwise be the case. But a bit of context is necessary here: the labour force has been growing much faster than employment over the past year (2.7 per cent year over year compared to 1.8 per cent in the latest data), leading to a 0.9 percentage point rise in the unemployment rate to 6.5 per cent over the past year. 

We need to consider what will happen to both quantities under the new plan. Yes, labour force growth will be slower, but it will likely still be positive (from students acquiring permanent residence and job-focused economic migration being given a higher priority than before). At the same time, slower immigration implies a significant hit to labour demand due to the impact on aggregate growth and consumption. So, the direction of travel of the unemployment rate compared to the previous is not necessarily much changed, maybe only a little slower to loosen on the margin.